Thursday, 1 June 2017

Does the EU Need a Trade Promotion Authority Mechanism?

This past spring, I had the opportunity to spend a couple of months in Washington, DC as a DAAD/AICGS Fellow at the American Institute for Contemporary German Studies (AICGS) in Washington, DC. I'm still working on an essay detailing the work I did there, but I've been following a number of developments in transatlantic trade relations. 

I penned a short piece for AICGS linked here. Space limitations meant I had to cut it down. The slightly longer version appears below.


It’s hard to believe, but governance of the European Union just got even more complicated last week. On May 16, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) issued its ruling over which European institutions had jurisdiction—“competence,” in the EU’s terminology—over the different provisions of the EU-Singapore Free Trade Agreement (Singapore FTA). European trade politics have been roiled by a series of controversies over who has the authority to bargain over the terms of trade agreements, the content of which increasingly reach deep into basic governance, including the state’s power to regulate.


In the midst of negotiating trade agreements with a number of different countries, the European Commission in July 2015 asked the ECJ to have a look at the proposed Singapore FTA and sort out which areas of the agreement were exclusively under the Commission’s jurisdiction, and which were under the jurisdiction of member states? According to the ECJ, it’s a “mixed” bag. In most areas-- tariffs and nontariff barriers for goods and services, intellectual property protections, investment, public procurement, competition and sustainable development—the Court ruled the Commission has exclusive jurisdiction. Yet, the ECJ ruled that the Commission had to get the approval of each Member State government for any agreement that included investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) mechanisms such as those in the Singapore FTA.

It wasn’t supposed to be this way. Many Europeans hoped the 2009 Lisbon Treaty had finally brought to fruition the long-held goal of a common front in Europe’s international economic relations. Henceforth, the Commission would negotiate on all issues on behalf of all member states. Indeed, Articles 3 and 207 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU, which Lisbon amended) is relatively explicit about the Union’s jurisdiction over external economic relations. Yet, Article 4 of the TFEU also mandates that in areas of shared competence between the EU and member states, negotiated treaties must be submitted to member states to receive their consent. As controversy brewed over pending FTA arrangements in 2015, the Commission decided to ask the ECJ for a ruling on all of this.

Implications may not matter for a while.
The ECJ’s ruling seemingly presents the European Commission with a stark choice; negotiate future agreements without ISDS as part of investment chapters, or submit completed agreements to each member state government for ratification. The first option would overturn decades of EU practice--Germany invented investment protection agreements in the late 1950s—and probably renders proposed trade negotiations with the United States a non-starter. Equally unpalatable, however, is the notion of submitting completed agreements to each European government for separate ratification.

How will states that embark on years of negotiations with Brussels be assured member states won’t reject a completed deal? How can the EU’s interlocutors be assured member states won’t make new demands at the ratification stage? The EU is big. Most of its potential trading partners are small. What country wants to pour resources into negotiating with the EU if member states can move the goal posts after the fact?

An unhappy Canadian trade minister
In many ways, we’ve already seen this movie. The Commission’s legal position in the Singapore case before the ECJ was that no post-agreement approval from member states was required; the Lisbon Treaty had concentrated that authority in the Commission. Full stop. Yet, in July 2016, the Commission nevertheless decided to propose the Canada-EU Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA) as a “mixed agreement” wherein member states would need to approve it after negotiations were complete. In October 2016, the approval process in Belgium went awry when the enclave of Wallonia decided they didn’t like the CETA.  Many were taken aback, not the least of which were Canadians. If the EU couldn’t successfully complete an agreement with Canada, with whom could they complete one with?

American “Fast Track”

The United States confronts a similar, but arguably more difficult set of problems. The ECJ ruling affirmed the jurisdiction of 28 (soon to be 27) member states to approve of ISDS, but left remaining authority over trade in the hands of the Commission. The U.S. Constitution, by contrast, assigns the legislative branch exclusive jurisdiction over all aspects of foreign commercial relations (the so-called enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8). The lure of enhanced U.S. market access is great, but the prospect of negotiating with 435 Members of the House of Representatives is daunting.

Trade Policy Infamy: Rep. Hawley and Sen. Smoot
Prior to 1934, the U.S. Congress was much more directly involved in setting the terms of commercial relations with foreigners. The results were often disastrous; anyone remember the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930? Since 1934, the U.S. Congress has periodically delegated its constitutional authority over “commerce with foreign nations” to the executive branch under specific, pre-negotiated terms and time limits. That authority has been granted under different guises in the postwar years, most notably under the terms of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA). In 1974, President Nixon sought renewed authority from Congress to bargain in the Tokyo Round of the General Agreements on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). What emerged was a mechanism popularly known as “Fast Track” in which Congress set the general limitations under which the President could bargain in exchange for an “up or down vote” once the completed agreement was brought back for approval by Congress—no amendments would be permitted.

Linked here is shameless bit of self-promotion to a piece of mine on this topic.

It was a delegation of power that worked for both branches of government; the President received a credible set of trade tools for the foreign policy tool chest, Congress absolved itself of collective action problems over a policy area in which parochial interests prevailed, but still had plenty of opportunity to weigh in legislatively on what the president had done. Importantly, Fast Track, known since 2002 as Trade Promotion Authority (TPA), has permitted the President to credibly claim that Members of Congress unhappy with specific provisions will not undermine hard-won negotiated agreements after the fact.

Europe isn’t the U.S., but….

The Lisbon Treaty was to have resolved these issues, but the ECJ decision on ISDS has determined otherwise. Governance in the European Union is obviously different than the United States; 28 sovereign states are not the same as 435 legislators. However, the reason a TPA-like process now makes sense for Europe is that the principle of delegation to a single negotiator is the same. If 435 Members of Congress can collectively agree to the terms over which they delegate broad swaths of statutory authority to the President, why couldn’t 28 member states do the same with the European Commission over the single issue of ISDS?

One major outcome of the controversy over the CETA was affirmation by all member states that ISDS should remain a part of the investment provisions of European trade agreements. Indeed, the terms of the CETA as well as the Commission’s proposal for both an“investment court” and an appellate mechanism in future agreements are important evolutions of the terms of ISDS. The ECJ’s ruling reflects concerns that ISDS rulings not undermine or circumvent either EU or Member State law. Such concerns about ISDS are widely held and why there have been important innovations in the application of investment rules over the past decade, including to the parameters of the U.S. Model Bilateral Investment Treaty (BIT).

Trade as a Trojan Horse?
Finally, in the United States, TPA also helps overcome some of the nasty contemporary politics of trade and investment liberalization. Members of Congress are individually not predisposed to liberalizing trade and investment, particularly when the adjustment costs from liberalization are highly concentrated. The advent of TPA allows individual Members to collectively agree on the general terms of negotiations in advance, thereby allowing Congress to pursue a generally liberalizing orientation to trade and investment. Both the pre-negotiation and the post-negotiation “up or down vote” avoids the Wallonian situation with the CETA by permitting complaints about process to be registered without having an agreement held hostage to specific or unrelated concerns.

Wallonians were ostensibly concerned about the CETA’s impact on agriculture, but the real target of their ire was Brussels and longer-standing debates about both Belgian and EU governance. A European version of TPA would permit those complaints to be heard before the Commission embarked on negotiations, giving the Commission the same added credibility and negotiating leverage a U.S. President enjoys with potential trading partners when armed with TPA. Such a process need not be complicated, and could be added to the process by which the Commission is empowered to negotiate through the Council of the EU and consults with the European Parliament. Alternatively, the Commission could embark upon the formalization of a Model BIT with language and institutions acceptable to all member states to be readily included as part of broader negotiations. Importantly, EU TPA would give member states one last “up or down” bite at the apple-- albeit a higher stakes bite since it would be a rejection of the entire deal rather than components.

The point is to deal with investment and ISDS up front, not after the fact. If the United States can deal with the entire menu of issues that now make up the global trade and investment agenda, certainly Europe could adopt a process of pre-delegated authority from member states to the Commission that could do the same for investment.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Redefining the Floor....Down

I was scrolling through some YouTube clips the other day and came across the great Seinfeld episode in which Frank Costanza invites Seinfeld...